Effects of Iran's WTO Accession on the
Cement Industry: A Dynamic Disequilibrium Adjustment Model (DDAM) of Simultaneous
Equations
Bijan Bidabad[1]
Nahid Kalbasi Anaraki[2]
Abstract
Many
companies around the globe are re-examining their business operations to
explore profitable growth in international markets.The attractiveness of the
membership in WTO can be recognized not only in the growing number of its
members but also as a result of increasing access to potential markets around
the world. Iranian economy suffers from huge inefficiency in its trade
relationships with other countries due to import compression policy and strict
import controls. Iran's import profile is heavily skewed towards those tradable
that are not strongly under the effects of WTO, indicating protectionism policy
in the industry sector. Besides the need for easing protectionism, the emphasis
placed on the growth of non-oil exports and reducing oil dependency as an
objective in the five-year development plans provides a strong argument for
joining WTO. Measuring technical efficiency in the cement industry in Iran
suggests that companies with export-orientation policy have potentials to
succeed in increasing their technical efficiency.The new discovering realm of
WTO for Iran's trade policy has been evaluated in this paper. The pros and cons
for joining induced us to investigate the effects of Iran's membership on the
cement industry. By designing a dynamic disequilibrium adjustment model (DDAM),
we use annual data for the period 1963-2002 to estimate a simultaneous system
of econometric equations including cement supply, exports, imports, and
consumption functions in order to quantify the effects of joining on the cement
industry of Iran. One of the main challenges confronting the Iranian cement
industry is to improve the competitiveness of the industry by reducing the
subsidies, removing restrictions, and price controls. Indeed, the experience of
other counties after joining WTO portrays a conflicting profile on the effects
of accession on domestic economies. While some countries have developed
important trading partners, others have suffered due to the loss of domestic
industries. In this paper, we intend to examine the hypothesis of whether
reducing the tariff rates will promote Iranian cement industry. The results
reveal that joining WTO has negligible effects on consumption, production, and
exports, though, will raise imports substantially.
Keywords: Cement Economics, Dynamic Disequilibrium
Adjustment Model, DDAM, WTO, Econometric Model
1. Introduction
Iran
has a special geographical advantage regarding mining products international
trade due to locating in the Persian Gulf region with high potentials since
mineral products have been among the top ten imports of the Persian Gulf
region. Due to import compression policy and strict import controls, Iran's
import as a share of GDP is relatively low. Moreover, her import profile is
heavily skewed towards bulk foodstuffs and essential capital goods, reflecting
recent currency shortage, import bans on many products and heavily protected
industrial base. However, higher oil revenue since 2000 has eased pressures on
Iran's debt obligations, permitting the growth of imports in the essential
goods. Though, the cement imports as a share of GDP still stands at a very low
level and is estimated to reach 0.025% in 2004.�
Iran's
cement is a 70 years old industry. The Iranian cement industry dates back to
1993 when the first manufacture established in Rai city. Trends of consumption,
production, and trade show that Iran has a more or less closed cement economy
due to import restrictions and export bans in specific years. As fluctuations
of cement demand and supply clarify, whenever the price of oil grows up, demand
increases due to increasing government development expenditures. As a result,
excess demand appears, cement price increases and the import of cement grows
up. To respond to the excess demand, cement producers try to enlarge cement
production capacity with some lags, and after few years excess demand is
removed by domestic supply, instead of imports. For many years, this was the
case for the Iranian economy. According to this dynamic procedure, we try to
build up a dynamic disequilibrium adjustment model (DDAM) to explain this
phenomenon. But before going through this procedure, we will have a closer look
at the cement industry with an emphasis on its output and trade.
Production:
This section portrays a profile of the industry production. Cement output has
experienced sharp fluctuations during the period under investigation,
1963-2002. Though cement production has increased by an average annual growth
rate of 10 percent during the mentioned period, it stands at a very low level
compared with other developing countries like China, India, and Korea. Indeed,
the industry has produced above the nominal capacity due to demand pressures
and restricted imports. Over the period 1973-1978 with the oil shock and sharp
increase in oil revenues cement production increased dramatically. However,
after then and during the imposed war, the production plunged due to the war
damages and scarcity of foreign exchange resources. The industry experienced a
negative growth rate of -3.6% in 1988 due to unused capacity and reduction of
productivity. However, during the post-war era, the production turned to an
increasing trend due to the reconstruction activities in such a way that the
output growth reached 16.7 percent in 1990.
Supply
has exceeded the demand growth with the establishment of new plants and with
the reduction in government expenditures since 1997. However, lack of access to
international markets has induced cement producers to reduce their production
due to the restriction imposed on cement exports.
Imports and Exports:
Word trade of cement stands at a lower level than its production since the raw
material for production are abundant and generally found in most parts of the
world. Despite the low ratio of world cement trade to the world production (7
percent in 1995), the growth of the cement trade has exceeded that of output
due to the high volume of trade in South East Asia. Cement imports have been
close to zero during the period under investigation except for the mid-1970s
when Iran confronted with a sharp increase in its oil revenues. However, this
trend turned dramatically during 1975-1995, leaving the industry without any
competitors due to a high level of protection, which has adversely affected the
productivity of the industry.
With
the increase in the demand during the 1970s, domestic production failed to
respond the aggregate demand, and as a result of this failure, the cement
import increased substantially, recording a growth rate of 134% in 1977,
compared with the previous year. Though cement import has been relatively
stable during the 1980s and 1990s, it experienced gradual growth in the early
2000s due to reconstruction activities and higher growth of the real-estate
sector of the economy compared with other sectors.��
Indeed,
Iran's cement imports and exports have been subject to tariff and non-tariff
barriers. Despite the cement shortage during the war, exports were subject to
the permission of the ministries of commerce and mining. Although exports
incentives and tax exemptions were introduced in 1987, the instability of
policy decisions and export bans in specific years contributed to the low
growth of exports. For instance, the export of different types of cement and
clinker was abandoned in 1996 and 1997. However, the government was induced to
remove exports barriers in order to avoid greater loss of manufactures in the
following years.
Graph (1).
Pricing:
Administrative
controlled prices during the 1980s and 1990s have led to the low production of
cement industry compared with other developing countries. It is worthwhile
mentioning that a major factor contributing to cement prices is personnel
expenses, which makes up 34 to 42 percent of the total costs, whereas the share
of raw materials in total costs does not exceed 6 to 7 percent. The share of
energy expenses and foreign exchange resources amounts to 18 and 14 percent of
total costs, respectively.
During
the post-war era, the distribution and pricing policy was under the control of
the government through the "Cement Planning Committee" established in
the management and planning organization (MPO). According to the regulations
approved by this committee, cement producers were obliged to deliver their
products to the ministry of commerce. With the end of the war in 1988, the
distribution came under the control of the ministry of industries within the
framework of a rationing system, and the share of the private sector, capital
expenditures, and public sector amounted to 50, 40, and 10 percent,
respectively.�
A
major challenge confronting the Iranian cement industry is administrative
controlled prices. As it is seen in Table (1), controlled prices have been
fixed for a long period of time during 1982-87 and have huge gaps with
international prices. For instance, the controlled price in Iran has been $17.1
per ton, compared with $78.5 of the world price in 2000, which is almost less
than one-fourth of the world price. Indeed, the prices have been kept at very
low levels artificially as a result of the high amount of revealed and
disguised subsidies which have been allocated through the central government.
With
the exchange rate unification in 1990-91, and due to the increasing gap between
the controlled and mark-up prices, there has been increasing pressures on
domestic prices. With the start of the privatization program and the increase
in the personnel and energy expenses, and with the increasing gap of the
official exchange rate with the parallel black market exchange rate, the
loss-making enterprises were unable to bear depreciation costs and as a result
prices were liberalized in 1992, though still stand at much lower level than
the world prices. Since then, the equilibrium prices have been set through
adding the book price with a margin profit rate set by the "Production and
Distribution of Cement Committee" including the members of
"Protection of Producers and Consumers Organization (PPCO)", ministry
of industry and management and planning organization (MPO). Meanwhile,
producers were allowed to distribute the production of higher than 90 percent
of the nominal capacity and the cement enterprises were obliged to pay $ 0.9 to
the ministry of industries for each ton of cement they deliver in order to help
the cement projects. In addition, the PPCO received the following share from
each ton of sold prices.
Share
of PPCO=.9[sold price � (mark-up price+5000Rls)]
However,
the consumer price was calculated by adding up the mark-up price to 15 percent
margin of profit and 1 percent municipalities' fee, 2 percent ministry of
education fees, and $ 0.5 for helping the ministry of economic affairs and
finance.
Although
considering 15 percent margin of profit rate for produces has alleviated the
financing problem of energy inputs and personnel expenses, this method of
pricing has failed to cover the depreciation costs. In addition, the prices are
lower for the older plants due to lower mark-up prices.
As
Table (1) suggests, the price of cement has been relatively stable during the
post-war period throughout 1982-1990. However, since the early 1990s, the
controlled price has jumped up dramatically and has reached $ 17.1 in 2000,
which is around one-fourth of the world price, $78.5.
Table (1) - Iran's cement controlled prices compared with the
world prices |
|||
Year |
Controlled
prices per ton in Rials |
$
Price per ton in Iran |
World
price ($ per ton) |
1982 |
3100 |
24.1 |
56.69 |
1983 |
3100 |
23.2 |
55.61 |
1984 |
3100 |
22.2 |
57.18 |
1985 |
3700 |
27.4 |
55.92 |
1986 |
3700 |
31.6 |
54.78 |
1987 |
3700 |
23.5 |
54.41 |
1988 |
4200 |
16.2 |
54.80 |
1989 |
4200 |
13.4 |
54.80 |
1990 |
4200 |
10.07 |
55.34 |
1991 |
10000 |
17.7 |
55.46 |
1992 |
10500 |
14.9 |
55.30 |
1993 |
20000 |
18.7 |
56.36 |
1994 |
25000 |
15.2 |
61.88 |
1995 |
33500 |
16.6 |
67.84 |
1996 |
42000 |
17.7 |
70.89 |
1997 |
55000 |
19.1 |
73.46 |
1998 |
71500 |
20.7 |
76.45 |
1999 |
85800 |
17.7 |
78.27 |
2000 |
102960 |
17.1 |
78.56 |
Graph 2. Iran's cement controlled prices
and the wholesale price index of cement Iran�s
domestic and world cement prices (ton/dollar)
2. Literature Review
Unfortunately,
little empirical study has been carried out on the cement industry of Iran.
Ramin Dadras (1999) tries to measure the technical efficiency of the industry,
using Stochastic Frontier Translog Production and Cobb-Douglas functions.[3]
The estimated results suggest that the inefficiency has increased during the
time, and the ownership type and presence of exports affect the efficiency of
the industry. Moreover, the estimated elasticities for the Translog function
suggest increasing returns to scale in the cement industry. The estimated
elasticities with respect to capital and labor according to the Translog
function are 0.82 and 0.22, respectively. The estimated technical efficiency of
the industry according to the Translog function and Cobb-Douglas functions
amounts to 0.87 and 0.85, respectively. Put differently; the industry has
produced 13 percent less than it could, given the amount of inputs and energy.
As
it is seen in Table (2), mean of efficiency has jumped up since 1992, with the
start of the First Five Year Development Plan. However, since 1994, the
industry has experienced a decreasing trend of technical efficiency. This
shift, in turn, is attributed to the excess supply and to a substantial
reduction in government expenditures in infrastructure and real estate sectors.
As a result of the excess supply, the number of enterprises forced to export
their products increased from 8 in 1994 to 13 in 1996. However, cement export
bans in 1996 acted as a slash to the efficiency of the industry. It is
worthwhile mentioning that some of the enterprises have experienced stable
efficiency during the period under investigation. For example, Fars Cement and
Sepahan Cement enterprises have experienced stable efficiency during the time
and the highest amount of efficiency in the sample, whereas Khazar Cement Co. had
the lowest efficiency score.
Since
1994 with the entry of the cement enterprises to the Tehran Stock Exchange
(TSE) efficiency has decreased substantially. However, one cannot argue that
the decreasing trend of efficiency can be attributed to the accession to TSE.
Indeed, one of the main reasons for the decreasing trend of efficiency is the
instability of regulations governing exports of the industry, particularly,
exports bans in 1996 and 1997.������
Table
(2)-Technical efficiency of the cement industry in Iran during 1991-1997
� |
1991 |
1992 |
1993 |
1994 |
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
Number of plants |
9 |
13 |
14 |
15 |
16 |
16 |
16 |
Mean Efficiency |
0.80 |
0.90 |
0.91 |
0.89 |
0.87 |
0.88 |
0.85 |
Standard Deviation |
0.10 |
0.06 |
0.05 |
0.06 |
0.16 |
0.14 |
0.11 |
Minimum |
0.59 |
0.73 |
0.76 |
0.73 |
0.27 |
0.40 |
0.50 |
Maximum |
0.93 |
0.95 |
0.95 |
0.95 |
0.95 |
0.96 |
0.94 |
Source:
Dadras, Ramin, "Measuring the technical efficiency of the cement industry
in Iran, a dissertation guided by� B. H.
Zonooz, Allameh University, 1999
�����������
In
another study, Morteza Sameti (1995)[4]
measures the efficiency of cement industry in different sectors. His sample includes
four cement companies, two public enterprises, one private, and one cement
company affiliated to the Mostazafan and Janbazan Foundation, which is a
semi-government organization. He uses a Cobb-Douglas production function to
measure the efficiency of the production. The estimated results suggest that
the elasticity of production with respect to the labor force for Tehran Cement
Company, which is affiliated to the Foundation, has had the highest elasticity
score. The private cement company, Shargh Cement Co. stands at the second
level, and finally, the public sector companies have had the lowest
elasticities.�
He
also has estimated the productivity of the labor force in different companies.
His results indicate the highest level of labor productivity in Tehran Cement
Co. and the lowest level in public sectors companies. However, with respect to
capital productivity, the private sector company has experienced the highest
productivity level.
Finally,
a long-run total cost function has been estimated with pooling data on
different companies with different types of ownership. The estimated results
indicate that the Tehran Cement company has had the lowest production costs and
then the private sector and public sector companies stood at the second and third
levels, supporting the estimated results of productivity. Put differently,
companies with higher productivity have experienced lower production costs.
Indeed, the estimated results suggest that public sector enterprises confront
with higher costs since they have been assured of receiving a large amount of
government subsidies and has taken no important invention to reduce their
operating costs.
WTO and countries experiences
The
treaty negotiated during the Uruguay round established the WTO, the international
institution to govern the world trade. The success of GATT as a dynamic
institution that has fostered dramatic increase in worldwide trade lies in its
founding principles of most favored nations treatment (MFNT), voluntary export
restrictions (VERs), orderly marketing arrangements (OMAs), rules of origin,
government procurement, safety rules, market access commitments and reciprocity
and non-discrimination. Thus, nondiscrimination extends the benefits of a
reciprocal tariff reduction beyond the two parties. Nondiscrimination is a
convenient way to reduce the complexity of international trade relations. As an
importer, a country can charge a single nondiscriminatory tariff on imports
from all countries, or it can set different tariffs on imports from different
countries. Under a nondiscriminatory tariff system, imports will be sourced
from the lowest-cost producers in the world. When a country uses a
nondiscriminatory tariff, this facilitates the allocation of resources
worldwide to their most productive uses.
�
Countries'
experiences portray a contradictory profile. While some countries like China
have benefited from joining WTO, others have suffered due to the loss of
domestic industries. In China, foreign investment is playing an increasingly
important role in shaping up the Chinese market. In 1998, there were 287
foreign-invested enterprises accounting for about 3% of all cement producers
and 15% of national output. China is the world's second-largest cement
exporter, accounting for about 17% of total global cement trade. China had cut
the average tariff level of imported goods from 15.3 percent to 12 percent in
2002; this reduction is fully in conformity with the commitment China has made
for its accession to the World Trade Organization.� Indeed, WTO accession should not have much of
an impact on the cement industry, as a tariff on cement and clinker dropped
only from 12 percent to 10 percent in 2001 and is not due to falling any
further. In sum, China's experience reveals a success story because domestic
protection has not stood at high levels before joining WTO.�
��
Taiwan
is another success story. Before the accession, the average levels of tariffs
on imports of industrial and agricultural products into Taiwan were 6.03 and
20.02 percent, respectively. Upon accession (2002), the two figures were
reduced to 5.78 and 14.01 percent, respectively.� Following the completion of all the scheduled
tariff reductions on the 3470, industrial and 1021 agriculture products for
which Taiwan has made commitments; the average levels of tariffs applied on
industrial and agricultural products fell further to 4.15 and 12.86 percent,
respectively. The economic impact of its WTO membership on the economies of its
trading partners, as well as Taiwan itself, will be worth billions of dollars
annually. According to a recent report by the Council of Economic Planning and
Development (CEPD), Taiwan's GDP is likely to expand by an additional 0.77-4.7
percent in the first five to ten years of WTO membership.
Others,
like Indonesia, confronts a possible crisis. When the crisis was at its peak in
1998 in Indonesia, the utilization rent of cement industry went down to 50
percent. This forced the producer to export at lower margins than those
available in the domestic market. Indonesia exported some 4.5 million tons of
cement and clinker in 1998 following the plunge in domestic demand, while
production reached 22 million tons per year. The increasing cement exports
since the crisis pushed export's share of total cement production from 1
percent in 1996 to 33 percent in 1999. Though there was an increase in exports,
the country's total cement production continued to decrease as domestic
consumption dwindled.� Now that
increasing domestic demand has pushed up the cement industry back to its
pre-crisis levels, the Indonesian Cement Association (ASI) has signaled that
cement exports would likely decrease. Last year, exports reached around 8
million tons. However, the increasing domestic demand could bring about a
rising crisis in the years to come if the present production capacity is not
increased. As itself, has projected a problem will rise in the cement supply in
the coming years because the growth of product capacities would be less than
the average of 3-5 percent growth rate of demand. To prevent a possible crisis,
new plants, and more supply of raw materials are needed. To encourage
investment, the government could provide such incentives as tax holidays.��
WTO
membership and associated trade liberalization are crucial for the Persian Gulf
region's future economic prospect, lifting economic growth and boosting foreign
investor confidence. Oman, Saudi Arabia, and Yemen have applied for membership
and are negotiating entry conditions, although Yemen's accession is in its
infancy. Iran's application for WTO membership has not been scheduled for
consideration due to US opposition. Indeed, WTO membership is an important
driver of reform, limiting the amount of protection. Trade liberalization,
particularly elimination of subsidies, protection of intellectual property
rights, and equal treatments for domestic and foreign companies are all
requirements of WTO memberships.� Members
also must remove non-tariff barriers, such as certification, licensing, government
procurements, and inspections not in accordance with WTO rules.�� Oman's accession is imminent. The accession
process has driven major reforms. Oman has agreed to liberalize tariff and bind
tariff commitments for agricultural exports as well as minerals, cars,
information technology products, chemicals, paper products, and construction
materials. Oman has also agreed on no tax discrimination between domestic and
foreign companies and has increased foreign ownership limit from 49 percent to
70 percent.
Saudi
Arabia WTO accession has important domestic and regional implications, given
the Saudi economy's size. Saudi Arabia's unilateral foreign investment
liberalization announcement in April 2000 and its improved tax treatment for
foreign companies already have placed the region countries like UAE under
pressure to improve their treatment of foreign investors. Bilaterally agreed
market access improvements, which will apply to all WTO members, will yield
significant benefits. Multilateral negotiations also could yield major
improvements in access to the Saudi Arabia market via reduced agriculture
subsidies, fewer quantitative restriction, improved intellectual property
rights, equal tax treatment for domestic and foreign companies, and improved
customs procedures.
Indeed,
countries' experiences reveal that a crucial factor affecting success story of countries
is the structure of the domestic industry and the level of protection on the
domestic industry before joining WTO. Countries that have already reduced their
tariff rates before joining WTO more likely will benefit from entry, though,
countries with high tariff rates that need to liberalize their domestic markets
to imports suddenly will more likely confront with potential losses.�
��
Tariff and non-tariff barriers in Iran
Tariff
barriers vary substantially across the Persian Gulf economies; Kuwait and the
UAE have the lowest average tariffs around 3.5 percent, and Saudi Arabia has
had the highest tariff rates among Arab countries. In the UAE, most tariffs are
4 percent, although around 75 percent of import is duty-free including
foodstuffs, medicines and public sector imports.� Saudi Arabia's simple average tariff rate is
12.5 percent. Imports of basic foodstuffs and medicines are duty-free, with a
general 12 percent tariff on most other imports, and a 20 percent tariff on
many imports which also are produced locally.
Qatar:
The general
tariff rate is 4 percent, but tariffs of 20 to 30 percent apply to goods
competing with local products such as cement, steel, and urea.
Bahrain:
Imports of raw
materials, semi-manufactured goods, and products for development projects or
re-exports are duty-free. Tariff starts at 5 percent on foodstuffs and
necessities, and as in many other regional economies, much higher rates apply
to cigarettes (50 percent).
Oman: A wide range of essentials
consumer goods enter duty-free, as do industrial inputs. Luxury consuming
goods, including tea, coffee, and prepared foods, attract 15 percent tariff,
while cars incur 10 to 15 percent tariff rates depending on the engine size.
Yemen:
Since 1996, as
part of the IMF sponsored reform program, tariffs have fallen to the domain of
5 to 25 percent.
Iran: Most consumer goods imports incur
30 to 50 percent tariffs. Capital and intermediate goods attract lower tariffs,
while medicines, wheat, and other strategic/essential goods are duty-free, and
non-essential imports are often banned. Indeed, the cement industry has been
heavily regulated through tariff and non-tariff barriers on cement imports and
exports, resulting in a low level of trade compared with domestic production.
To review the tariff and non-tariff barriers in Iran, we focus on the data in
1999, the most recent available data on tariffs. According to export-import
regulations, goods and commodities are categorized under 21 sectors.
Table
(3) presents the minimum, maximum, and average tariff rates of different
categories in 1999. As it is seen, the lowest tariff rate applies to chemical
industries among different sectors. The cement industry in the fifth category
has experienced an average tariff rate of 35.7 percent. Indeed, the cement
industry has been relatively less protected than sectors like food industries
or textile; however, has been heavily protected compared with sectors like
chemical industries with an average tariff rate of 18.9 percent. Moreover, the
industry has confronted with export bans in specific years, especially in 1995
and 1996. Indeed, the high level of tariff and non-tariff barriers has
contributed to a low level of cement production in Iran.
Comparing
average tariff rates in Iran with other countries, as revealed in Table (4),
shows that Iran has experienced a much higher level of protection. For
instance, the average tariff rates in the industrial sector in Turkey,
Singapore, and Philippine amounts to 5.7, 2.7, and 9.1, respectively. Even
compared with Thailand with an average tariff rate of 43.7, and India with an
average tariff rate of 29.5, Iran has experienced much higher tariff rates in
some industries including food and textile. The matter of the fact is that
Iran's protectionism policy has been very intense compared with other
developing countries leading to smuggling and trafficking of goods due to the
high amount of subsidies allocated to some sectors through the central government.
With
a new era of international trade, many countries have reduced their tariff and
non-tariff barriers to be eligible to join WTO. The research studies carried
out in developing countries suggest that amount of reduction in tariff rates
vary substantially depending on trading partners, the composition of foreign
trade, the structure of the ownership, and the level of protection before
joining WTO.
Table
(3). Average tariff rates for different categories in Iran (1999)
Category |
Items |
No
of tariffs |
Min
tariff |
Max
tariff |
Average
tariff |
1 |
Animal and animal products |
201 |
0 |
180 |
62.3 |
2 |
Vegetables, fruits and wheat |
271 |
0 |
200 |
85.9 |
3 |
Soya bean oil and non-vegetarian� oil |
46 |
0 |
175 |
55.0 |
4 |
Food industry, beverage, and tobacco |
186 |
0 |
200 |
103.7 |
5 |
Mineral products |
148 |
5 |
110 |
22.6 |
6 |
Chemical industries and related items |
786 |
0 |
210 |
18.8 |
7 |
Crude rubber and caoutchouc |
198 |
5 |
215 |
38.5 |
8 |
Leather and leather made commodities |
74 |
5 |
215 |
127.1 |
9 |
Wood and wood products |
81 |
5 |
215 |
71.6 |
10 |
Paper and paper products |
148 |
5 |
135 |
37.9 |
11 |
Textile and related items |
824 |
10 |
270 |
109.0 |
12 |
Shoes, umbrella, and sun-glasses |
55 |
120 |
220 |
204.7 |
13 |
Chalk, asbestos, tile, and glass |
147 |
5 |
220 |
78.3 |
14 |
Pearl. Precious stones and gold |
52 |
5 |
270 |
39.0 |
15 |
Non-precious stones |
571 |
5 |
325 |
43.7 |
16 |
Electronic instruments, tape records,
TV |
804 |
0 |
180 |
41.5 |
17 |
Transportation vehicles |
132 |
0 |
190 |
Na |
18 |
Optics, cameras, medical and surgery
instruments |
238 |
5 |
145 |
35.6 |
19 |
Guns and related items |
17 |
80 |
80 |
80 |
20 |
Sport goods and toys |
130 |
15 |
215 |
130.6 |
21 |
Paintings and
antiques |
7 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
Source:
Razini Ali, rationalizing tariff rates in Iran, trade research center, ministry
of commerce, 1999.
Table
(4)- Tariff commitments of selected countries for industrial products in 1999 |
|||
Member |
Percent of imports with bound tariffs |
Current mean industrial tariff |
Applied bound tariff |
Philippines |
67.4 |
9.1 |
21.3 |
Indonesia |
92.3 |
14.9 |
36.9 |
Malaysia |
79.3 |
9.4 |
8.9 |
Singapore |
96.5 |
2.7 |
6.9 |
Thailand |
67.4 |
43.7 |
27.3 |
Brazil |
100 |
18.3 |
27.7 |
Chile |
100 |
10.9 |
24.9 |
India |
69.3 |
29.5 |
34.2 |
Sri Lanka |
9.2 |
19.8 |
17.9 |
Turkey |
49.3 |
5.7 |
16.3 |
Zimbabwe |
13.6 |
20.5 |
23.6 |
Australia |
96.9 |
4.4 |
12.1 |
Canada |
99.8 |
3.2 |
4.3 |
European Union |
100 |
3.5 |
3.2 |
Korea |
89.9 |
7.8 |
6.9 |
Mexico |
100 |
12 |
33.3 |
United
States |
100 |
2.7 |
3.5 |
Source:www.cementdistribution.com/industryinfo/trade.html
Non-tariff barriers in Iran
The
Market Regulating Committee[5]
is in charge of cement pricing and has approved the following regulations in
2002 regarding the cement industry in Iran. According to these regulations, the
clinker price for the year 2003 is obtained by adding up the base price in 2002
to 15 percent growth rate. The amount of sale by each company should be
determined by a committee, which consists of the vice minister of commerce,
vice minister of industries and vice minister of housing. According to the
regulations approved by the cited committee, enterprises are obliged to use the
difference between controlled price and the equilibrium price for increasing
the capacity of the cement industry. Meanwhile, the main shareholders of the
cement industry including; Social Security Organization, Mostazafan and
Janbazan Foundation, and the National Bank of Iran are responsible for
importing cement or clinker according to the needs announced through the
above-mentioned committee.
The
controlled price will be set on a quarterly basis. In addition, the profit
margins for the wholesale and retail sellers will be determined by this
committee and will be approved by the Consumers and Producers Protection
Organization (CPPO). The ministry of industries will be in charge of
determining the cement prices in different enterprises, depending on the region
and the quality of production. All producers and distributors are subject to
administrative controlled prices. Moreover, the cement producers are
responsible for allocating a portion of their profits for financing the
difference in the controlled price and the import price of cement and clinker.
Ministry of industries is responsible for the imports of clinker and cement.
The Management and Planning Organization (MPO) and the Central Bank of Iran
(CBI) are committed to providing financial facilities to respond to the needs
of establishment and especially for increasing the existent capacities.
However, white cement is excluded from the above-mentioned regulations.
As
it is seen, the cement industry in Iran is heavily regulated and protected
through different committees and organizations, which are involved in
determining administrative controlled prices and distribution mechanism. Indeed,
the industry has failed to respond to domestic demand due to the existence of
tariff and non-tariff barriers. Accession to the World Trade Organization (WTO)
requires removing the controlled prices, quantitative restrictions, and bans on
imports and exports, which are all requirements for improving the
competitiveness of the industry. Indeed, joining the WTO requires carrying out
essential reforms to reduce the tariff rates substantially. To assess the
effects of tariff reduction on the cement industry, the next section develops a
structural system of equations, including supply, demand, exports, imports, and
prices.�
Future Trade Prospects
Trade
prospects are good in the short-run and medium term. During 2000-2003 high oil
prices have driven rapid import growth in the Persian Gulf economies, though
beyond 2003, this factor may not sustain continued growth. In the medium term,
WTO is becoming an increasingly important force for liberalization in the
region, reducing tariff and removing non-tariff barriers, improving
intellectual property right protection, deregulating and liberalizing agency
arrangements and opening rapidly growing sectors such as telecommunications and
e-technologies. Its influence is likely to increase if Saudi Arabia's accession
is successful. Common GCC external tariffs may raise average tariffs in some of
the region's most open economies, like the UAE and Kuwait; however, increased
integration also can promote intra-regional trade and hence manufacturer's
ability to move beyond the Gulf region from base manufacturing, the oil.
In
the medium term, Iran may become a substantially more important trading nation
in the Persian Gulf region since she has rapid population growth and is willing
to carry out economic reforms in accordance with WTO agreements.
����������� �
3. Methodology
To
determine the quantitative effects of Iran's joining WTO on her cement industry
we try to build up a dynamic disequilibrium adjustment model (DDAM) to
investigate the effects of tariff reductions on production, consumption, and
trade, with emphasis on simultaneous domestic price effect in changing domestic
production and consumption. The sample under investigation covers the period
1963-2002. The data on the cement industry has been obtained from the cement
companies and� macroeconomic data
including GDP , cement wholesale price index, and Iran's effective exchange
rate has been obtained from the data bank of the Central Bank of Iran. The
world production and prices have been obtained from International Trade
Statistics.�
�
List of Variables
IRYCD=Iran's
cement output (domestic supply)
IRIMP=Iran's
cement imports in tons
IREXP=Iran's
cement exports
WPRICE=World
price of cement
IRPRICE=Iran's
approved cement price (Rials per ton)
IRWPRICE=Iran's
cement wholesale price index
IRGDP=Iran's
GDP at constant factor prices
IRGDPNF=Non
oil GDP at factor costs
IREENOIL=Iran's
effective exchange rate (Units of Rials per U.S. dollars)
EXCESS=Change
in cement inventory in Iran
NCAPACITY=nominal
capacity of cement production in Iran
CONSD=Cement
consumption of domestic production
Variables
starting with "D" and following with two or four digit numbers are
dummy variables whose values are one for the specific period denoted by digits
and zero otherwise. The proposed DDAM consists of the following equations:
IRIMP=C(10)+C(11)*IRGDP+C(12)*IREENOIL*WPRICE/IRWPRICE+C(13)*IRIMP(-1)+
C(14)*D5972*IRIMP(-1)+C(15)*D77+C(16)*D79+C(76)*D7905
IREXP=(1-D7286)*(C(21)*NCAPACITY+C(22)*IREENOIL*WPRICE/IRWPRICE+
C(23)*IREXP(-1))+C(24)*D0205+C(25)*D71
LOG(IRYCD)=C(30)+C(31)*LOG(IRWPRICE)+C(32)*LOG(NCAPACITY)+
C(33)*LOG(IRYCD(-1))
LOG(CONSD)=C(40)+C(41)*LOG(IRWPRICE)+C(42)*LOG(IRGDPNF)+C(43)*@TREND+
C(44)*D5978
LOG(IRWPRICE)
=(C(51)*EXCESS+C(52)*LOG(IRWPRICE(-1)))*(1+C(53)*D9405)
EXCESS=IRYCD+IRIMP-CONSD-IREXP
TBALANCE
= IREXP-IRIMP
The
interaction mechanism of the model is very simple. Import, export and domestic
production and consumption of cement are determined by the first fourth
equations, and the sixth identity calculates changes in the inventory of
cement. Price of cement is determined by the fifth equation, which is a
difference equation and can oscillate in varieties of ways based on its lags
structure, parameters' signs and magnitudes. Cement price simultaneously is
determined by the existence of this variable in the first four equations.�
4. Estimated Results
All
equations have been estimated by OLS method. The estimated results suggest, as
presented in Table (5) that all statistics are econometrically meaningful and
statistically significant in all equations.
The
estimated results suggest that cement import covaries positively and
significantly with GDP and negatively with the real effective exchange rate.
Export equation reveals the fact that cement export is significantly and
positively related to nominal capacity and real effective exchange rate.�
Cement
production covaries positively and significantly with the cement wholesale
price index through the size of influence is negligible. However, the nominal
capacity has a positive and significant influence on domestic production.
Domestic consumption is negatively and significantly related to the cement
wholesale price index, as expected and positively and significantly in relation
to GDP.
Table
(5). Estimated results for the DDAM for the cement industry of Iran
Independent
variable |
IRIMP |
IREXP |
IRYCD |
CONSD |
IRWPRICE |
IRGDP |
1.61 (4.12) |
|
|
|
|
IRGDPNF |
|
|
|
0.91 (17.08) |
|
IRENONOIL |
-167 (-3.4) |
27.6 (2.44) |
|
|
|
IRIMP (-1) |
0.55 (11.3) |
|
|
|
|
NCAPACITY |
|
0.69 (2.27) |
0.27 (3.87) |
|
|
IREXP(-1) |
|
0.32 (1.97) |
|
|
|
IRWPRICE |
|
|
0.02 (2.41) |
-0.20 (-7.51) |
1.08 (62.13) |
IRYCD(-1) |
|
|
0.59 (7.25) |
|
|
EXCESS |
|
|
|
|
8.46E-08 (2.55) |
R-Squared |
0.97 |
0.88 |
0.99 |
0.99 |
0.99 |
Adjusted R-squared |
0.97 |
0.87 |
0.99 |
0.99 |
0.99 |
Durbin-Watson |
1.29 |
1.76 |
2.10 |
1.34 |
1.20 |
To
analyze the effects of Iran's WTO accession on the Iranian cement industry we
solve the model for the period of 1993-2002 by stochastic simulation with 1000
replication to find out the baseline scenario which is used as a control
solution to compare with an alternative scenario which has been modified to measure
Iran's WTO joining effect. The result of the baseline solution model is
presented in Annex 1.�
Since
the data on tariff rate for the time period under investigation is not
available, to measure the effects of tariff reduction within the model, we decrease
book price of cement both for imports and exports to be in conformity with WTO
agreements. To do so, we multiply the real effective exchange rate variable in
both import demand and export supply equations of the model by
To
measure the amount of tariff reduction, we use pre and post WTO joining tariff
profiles for imports of industrial products by the country group as a proxy for
the tariff reduction rate. According to unbalanced tariff reductions for
developed and less developed countries, and regarding previous studies[6]
we adopt to apply 69% tariff reduction on Iran's import of cement from DCs and
14% tariff reduction for Iran's exports to DCs. Though these numbers are guess
estimates but can show the effects of joining WTO on Iran's cement economics.
Using stochastic simulation of model 2 with the same characteristics of model
1, regarding the sample period and 1000 replication, we produced the
alternative solution which can be compared with the control solution (Annex 3).
The
following graphs and tables compare the mean and standard deviations of these
two solutions. The results of the simulations are presented in Annex 4.
In
sum, the estimated results and simulations indicate that Iran's joining WTO:
�
Does
not affect her domestic cement consumption.
� Has negligible decreasing effects
on cement exports
� Will dramatically increase Iran's
cement imports
� Price adjustment is as dynamic as
changes in total cement demand and supply and will adjust itself more rapidly
after joining WTO
� Changes in domestic supply will
be negligible after joining WTO
�
All
in all, joining WTO may cause the cement trade deficit
4. Conclusion
Iran
has a unique geographical situation in the Persian Gulf region for boosting
trade in different commodities, especially minerals. Reducing oil dependency as
one of the main objectives of the Five Years Development Plans has induced the
Iranian officials to undertake some essential reforms in trade and government
policies. Though Iran still suffers from high levels of tariff and non-tariff
barriers on her trade relations and internal obstacles on domestic industries,
in the medium term, Iran may become a substantially more important trading
nation in the Persian Gulf region since she has rapid population growth and is
willing to carry out economic reforms.
The
administrative price controls besides import compression policy have
contributed to the low level of cement production. Iran's import profile is
heavily skewed towards those tradable that are not strongly under the effects
of WTO, indicating protectionism in the industry sector. Trade liberalization
that has been carried among the Persian Gulf region's economies provides a
supportive argument for Iran's accession to WTO. Since countries' experiences
provide a contradictory profile after joining WTO, this paper tried to
investigate the quantitative effects of the entry accession on the cement
industry of Iran.
To
do so, we developed a dynamic disequilibrium adjustment model (DDAM) with data
covering the period 1963-2002. Assuming 69 percent tariff reduction on Iran's
imports of cement from DCs and 14 percent tariff reduction for Iran's exports
to DCs after accession and applying stochastic dynamic simulation results for
the period 1993-2002 with one thousand replications suggest that Iran's
accession to WTO has negligible effects on her domestic consumption, production,
and exports, while it substantially raises its cement imports.
All
in all, the results suggest that Iran's WTO accession does not have tremendous
effects on its production, exports, and consumption. Though the entry may
accelerate cement imports. Since the cement is used as an essential input for
the industry and real-estate sectors, which has highly contributed to the GDP
growth in recent years, it is expected that it may contribute to a higher level
of economic growth in years to come.
To
pave the way for joining WTO, Iran has to take important measures to liberalize
controlled prices, to remove quantitative restrictions, and to deregulate the
industry in conformity with WTO arrangements.�
References
Balassa B. (1971).
The structure of protection in developing
countries. John Hopkins Press, Baltimore.
Baldwin,
Richard E. (2000), Regulatory protectionism developing nations, and a two-tier
world trade system.
Bidabad,
Bijan. (1994). Quantitative effects of
joining WTO on Iran industrial sector.
Bidabad,
Bijan.(1994). Designing an econometric
model to measure the changes in imports and exports of the industry sector ,
Chapter 5.
Bidabad,
Bijan; Mahshid Sherafati, Roohollah Mohammadi.(2014).Measuring Efficiency of
Production and Cost in Abyek Cement Factory Using Operational and Efficient
Production Functions. International Conference on Business Strategy and Social
Sciences (ICBSSS), Asian Economic and Social Society (AESS), Faculty of
Technology Management and Business, Universiti Tun Hussein Onn Malaysia, and
Pak Publishing Group. 16-17 August 2014, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.
������������ http://www.bidabad.com/doc/abyekfunction-en.pdf ��
Bidabad,
Bijan; Mahshid Sherafati, Roohollah Mohammadi.(2014).A Financial Model for
Economic Analysis of Cement Factory.
International Conference on Business Strategy and Social Sciences (ICBSSS),
Asian Economic and Social Society (AESS), Faculty of Technology Management and
Business, Universiti Tun Hussein Onn Malaysia, and Pak Publishing Group. 16-17
August 2014, Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia.
����
��������http://www.bidabad.com/doc/abyekanalysis-short-en.pdf
Bora,
B., A. Kuwahara, S., Laird. (2002). Quantification of non-tariff measures,
Policy issues in international trade and commodities, study series no. 18.
United Nations, Trade Analysis Branch, Division on International Trade in Goods
and Services, and Commodities, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), Geneva, Switzerland. http://r0.unctad.org/p166/module2002Bangk/Module4/boralairdkuwa.pdf
Borland,
B., 2000, Gulf 2000: The WTO and GCC, paper presented at the Gulf 2000: Energy
Infrastructure and Finance Conference, Abu Dhabi, 28 and 29 March
Bosworth, Malcom .(1999).
Non-Tariff measures as trade barriers: yesterday problem or what? Paper
prepared for the OECD workshop with non-member economies on barriers to trade
in goods and services in the post-Uruguay round context. Paris, 27-28
September.
Bouet,
A., L. Fontagne, M. Mimouni, X. Pichot (2001), Market access maps: A bilateral
and disaggregated measure of market access.
Corden W.M.� .(1971). The theory of protection. Clarendon
Press, Oxford.
Dadras,
R. 1999, 'Measuring the technical efficiency of the cement industry in Iran, a
dissertation guided by Dr. B. H. Zonooz, Allameh University, Tehran.
Deardorff,
A., R. Stern. (1998). The measurement of non-tariff barriers, OECD, Economic
Department Working Papers No. 179, OECD, Washington.
Fieleke N.S.
(1995) The Uruguay round of trade negotiations. Industrial and geographic
effects in the United States. New England economic review. Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston. July/August.
Fieleke N.S.
(1995) The Uruguay round of trade negotiations. Industrial and geographic
effects in the United States. New England economic review, Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, May/June.
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade.
�The results of the Uruguay round of multilateral trade negotiations�, Geneva,
November 1994.
Heller H.R. (1995)
International trade, theory and empirical evidence, prentice hall of India, New
Delhi.
http://heiwww.unige.ch/~baldwin/papers/NTBs_brookings_trade_forum00_baldwin.pdf
Intriligator M.D.
(1978). Econometric models, techniques, and applications. North-Holland
publishing company.
Mohammed
Reza Raf'ati, 1995, ' Iran's standing in Global Trade and Upshots of Membership
the GATT, Payame Darya (Economic-Scientific Monthly), Vol. 4, No.33, pp. 14-25.
Razini
Ali, rationalizing tariff rates in Iran, trade research center, ministry of
commerce, 1999.
Sameti,
M., 1995. 'Reducing Government Interventions', Ministry of Economic Affairs and
Finance, Tehran, Iran.
����� http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/communications/pdf/2001/washington/macmaps.pdf
����� http://www.nuca.ie.ufrj.br/infosucro/biblioteca/negociacoes/Baldwin_regulatory.pdf�
Annex 1
System:
SYS02 |
||||
Estimation
Method: Iterative Least Squares |
||||
Sample:
1963 2002 |
||||
Included
observations: 40 |
||||
Total
system (unbalanced) observations 196 |
||||
Convergence
achieved after 2 iterations |
||||
|
Coefficient |
Std.
Error |
t-Statistic |
Prob.� |
C(10) |
356713.0 |
89239.77 |
3.997242 |
0.0001 |
C(11) |
1.614763 |
0.391224 |
4.127468 |
0.0001 |
C(12) |
-167.8328 |
49.08161 |
-3.419465 |
0.0008 |
C(13) |
0.553647 |
0.048830 |
11.33823 |
0.0000 |
C(14) |
-2.844118 |
0.717737 |
-3.962618 |
0.0001 |
C(15) |
1575730. |
118637.0 |
13.28195 |
0.0000 |
C(16) |
-1029487. |
139216.0 |
-7.394891 |
0.0000 |
C(76) |
-465079.1 |
65039.66 |
-7.150699 |
0.0000 |
C(21) |
0.693379 |
0.305329 |
2.270925 |
0.0244 |
C(22) |
27.63896 |
11.29419 |
2.447184 |
0.0154 |
C(23) |
0.324899 |
0.164908 |
1.970181 |
0.0504 |
C(24) |
394125.0 |
47465.98 |
8.303316 |
0.0000 |
C(25) |
174850.0 |
45179.54 |
3.870114 |
0.0002 |
C(30) |
3.553863 |
0.626057 |
5.676581 |
0.0000 |
C(31) |
0.029530 |
0.012247 |
2.411316 |
0.0170 |
C(32) |
0.271043 |
0.069899 |
3.877621 |
0.0002 |
C(33) |
0.598896 |
0.082511 |
7.258341 |
0.0000 |
C(40) |
4.136804 |
0.553261 |
7.477131 |
0.0000 |
C(41) |
-0.208590 |
0.027749 |
-7.517172 |
0.0000 |
C(42) |
0.910048 |
0.053252 |
17.08955 |
0.0000 |
C(43) |
0.059990 |
0.006514 |
9.208956 |
0.0000 |
C(44) |
-0.267502 |
0.044555 |
-6.003929 |
0.0000 |
C(51) |
8.46E-08 |
3.31E-08 |
2.557616 |
0.0114 |
C(52) |
1.089052 |
0.017527 |
62.13742 |
0.0000 |
C(53) |
-0.040562 |
0.018605 |
-2.180109 |
0.0306 |
Determinant
residual covariance |
3.07E+12 |
|
|
|
Equation:
IRIMP=C(10)+C(11)*IRGDP+C(12)*IREENOIL*WPRICE /IRWPRICE+ |
||||
������
C(13)*IRIMP(-1)+C(14)*D5972*IRIMP(-1)+C(15)*D77+C(16)*D79+C(76)*D7905 |
||||
Observations:
39 |
||||
R-squared |
0.977260 |
��� Mean dependent var |
263560.7 |
|
Adjusted
R-squared |
0.972125 |
��� S.D. dependent var |
620654.5 |
|
S.E.
of regression |
103623.4 |
��� Sum squared resid |
3.33E+11 |
|
Durbin-Watson
stat |
1.296946 |
|
|
|
Equation:
IREXP=(1-D7286)*(C(21)*NCAPACITY+C(22)*IREENOIL |
||||
�������
*WPRICE/IRWPRICE+C(23)*IREXP(-1))+C(24)*D0205+C(25)*D71 |
||||
Observations:
39 |
||||
R-squared |
0.885778 |
��� Mean dependent var |
93074.18 |
|
Adjusted
R-squared |
0.872340 |
��� S.D. dependent var |
120420.2 |
|
S.E.
of regression |
43025.50 |
��� Sum squared resid |
6.29E+10 |
|
Durbin-Watson
stat |
1.767650 |
|
|
|
Equation:
LOG(IRYCD)=C(30)+C(31)*LOG(IRWPRICE)+C(32) |
||||
������� *LOG(NCAPACITY)+C(33)*LOG(IRYCD(-1)) |
||||
Observations:
39 |
||||
R-squared |
0.995544 |
��� Mean dependent var |
15.84935 |
|
Adjusted
R-squared |
0.995162 |
��� S.D. dependent var |
0.927457 |
|
S.E.
of regression |
0.064510 |
��� Sum squared resid |
0.145656 |
|
Durbin-Watson
stat |
2.109574 |
|
|
|
Equation:
LOG(CONSD)=C(40)+C(41)*LOG(IRWPRICE)+C(42) |
||||
�������
*LOG(IRGDPNF)+C(43)*@TREND+C(44)*D5978 |
||||
Observations:
40 |
||||
R-squared |
0.995519 |
��� Mean dependent var |
15.79203 |
|
Adjusted
R-squared |
0.995006 |
��� S.D. dependent var |
0.989941 |
|
S.E.
of regression |
0.069955 |
��� Sum squared resid |
0.171278 |
|
Durbin-Watson
stat |
1.347284 |
|
|
|
Equation:
LOG(IRWPRICE) =(C(51)*EXCESS+C(52)*LOG(IRWPRICE(-1)))*� (1+C(53)*D9405) |
||||
Observations:
39 |
||||
R-squared |
0.994469 |
��� Mean dependent var |
2.031391 |
|
Adjusted
R-squared |
0.994161 |
��� S.D. dependent var |
1.888493 |
|
S.E.
of regression |
0.144301 |
��� Sum squared resid |
0.749616 |
|
Durbin-Watson
stat |
1.205921 |
|
|
|
Annex 2. Model for Baseline Solution
IRIMP=356712.976885967+1.61476270618398*IRGDP-167.832811413045*IREENOIL*
WPRICE/IRWPRICE+0.553647193085624*IRIMP(-1)-2.84411769308308*D5972*IRIMP(-1)+1575730.35363319*D77-1029487.01407616*D79-465079.055437859*D7905
@INNOV
IRIMP� 103623.3858
IREXP=(1-
D7286)*(0.693379435212086*NCAPACITY+27.6389569885331*IREENOIL*
WPRICE/IRWPRICE+0.324898912988592*IREXP(-1))+394125.044423648* D0205+
174849.960849296*D71
@INNOV
IREXP� 43025.49704
LOG(IRYCD)=3.55386253259695+0.0295302269682137*LOG(IRWPRICE)+0.271043101241564*LOG(NCAPACITY)+0.598896470243663*LOG(IRYCD(-1))
@INNOV
IRYCD� 0.06451036764
LOG(CONSD)=4.13680392769509-0.20859037839689*LOG(IRWPRICE)+0.910047792543505*LOG(IRGDPNF)+0.0599895559828637*@TREND-0.267502133314843*D5978
@INNOV
CONSD� 0.06995458186
LOG(IRWPRICE)=(8.45645793256322e-08*EXCESS+1.08905173285413*LOG(IRWPRICE(-1)))*(1-0.0405615985167576*D9405)
@INNOV
IRWPRICE� 0.1443005985
@IDENTITY
EXCESS=IRYCD+IRIMP-CONSD-IREXP
@IDENTITY
TBALANCE=IREXP- IRIMP
Annex 3. Model for Alternative Scenario
Solution
IRIMP=356712.976885967+1.61476270618398*IRGDP-167.832811413045*(1-0.69)*
IREENOIL* WPRICE/IRWPRICE+0.553647193085624*IRIMP(-1)-2.84411769308308*
D5972*IRIMP(-1)+1575730.35363319*D77-1029487.01407616*D79-465079.055437859*D7905
@INNOV
IRIMP103623.3858
IREXP=(1-D7286)*(0.693379435212086*NCAPACITY+27.6389569885331*(1-0.14)*
IREENOIL*WPRICE/IRWPRICE+0.324898912988592*IREXP(-1))+
394125.044423648*D0205+174849.960849296*D71
@INNOV
IREXP43025.49704
LOG(IRYCD)=3.55386253259695+0.0295302269682137*LOG(IRWPRICE)+0.271043101241564*LOG(NCAPACITY)+0.598896470243663*LOG(IRYCD(-1))
@INNOV
IRYCD0.06451036764
LOG(CONSD)=4.13680392769509-0.20859037839689*LOG(IRWPRICE)+
0.910047792543505*LOG(IRGDPNF)+0.0599895559828637*@TREND-0.267502133314843*D5978
@INNOV
CONSD0.06995458186
LOG(IRWPRICE)=(8.45645793256322e-08*EXCESS+1.08905173285413*
LOG(IRWPRICE(-1)))*(1-0.0405615985167576*D9405)
@INNOV
IRWPRICE0.1443005985
@IDENTITY
EXCESS=IRYCD+IRIMP-CONSD-IREXP
@IDENTITY
TBALANCE=IREXP-IRIMP
Annex 4. Simulation results
|
1993 |
1994 |
1995 |
1996 |
1997 |
1998 |
1999 |
2000 |
2001 |
2002 |
CONSD |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
16206554 |
16266473 |
15678350 |
17107958 |
18931072 |
19583744 |
19500937 |
22095048 |
25268341 |
27401937 |
����� Baseline |
16037884 |
15902430 |
17018563 |
18799138 |
19654592 |
20660799 |
21119947 |
22179957 |
22987199 |
26442721 |
�������� S.E. |
1895308 |
1778554 |
1998893 |
2425842 |
2587788 |
2795845 |
2892428 |
3153050 |
3566378 |
4324011 |
����� Scenario 1 |
15976223 |
15679965 |
16906397 |
18632374 |
19564776 |
20407961 |
20885806 |
22170449 |
22716277 |
26485278 |
�������� S.E. |
1844899 |
1706401 |
1896838 |
2218463 |
2552745 |
2651939 |
2814842 |
3110629 |
3361313 |
4625671 |
EXCESS |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
-122047 |
-254573 |
484747 |
184983 |
-467738 |
-520582 |
-235484 |
-298363 |
-373231 |
-1201499 |
����� Baseline |
-653809 |
337059 |
-631364 |
-1932532 |
-1376182 |
-1178608 |
-490759 |
-763234 |
1109860 |
-57875 |
�������� S.E. |
2543281 |
2515181 |
2705736 |
3178829 |
3473077 |
3802322 |
3931406 |
4260335 |
4836064 |
6000669 |
����� Scenario 1 |
-353901 |
788030 |
-196046 |
-1405451 |
-1019106 |
-530351 |
47128 |
-413340 |
1691128 |
176323 |
�������� S.E. |
2475059 |
2410685 |
2555826 |
2890406 |
3327974 |
3506234 |
3732775 |
4017888 |
4483017 |
6098156 |
IREXP |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
111239 |
134488 |
197054 |
260388 |
235238 |
261208 |
122375 |
155087 |
194850 |
610693 |
����� Baseline |
86759 |
128144 |
152419 |
180749 |
206906 |
207866 |
225355 |
190251 |
183278 |
612082 |
�������� S.E. |
46090 |
46387 |
47534 |
53072 |
51064 |
53496 |
53706 |
60049 |
53014 |
63026 |
����� Scenario 1 |
78532 |
120113 |
138204 |
169730 |
194205 |
191684 |
210607 |
173976 |
173039 |
603892 |
�������� S.E. |
45263 |
45866 |
46397 |
47404 |
47280 |
47773 |
49995 |
53907 |
48096 |
60812 |
IRIMP |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
46985 |
7876 |
6205 |
7717 |
1369 |
917 |
4633 |
5906 |
8234 |
9944 |
����� Baseline |
98823 |
31597 |
-52485 |
-66917 |
-36401 |
-49132 |
-66666 |
-43403 |
101500 |
54936 |
�������� S.E. |
141048 |
143723 |
164024 |
190253 |
201540 |
218589 |
234663 |
251001 |
215611 |
291782 |
����� Scenario 1 |
291764 |
239516 |
210658 |
227560 |
251176 |
251709 |
251855 |
275379 |
333432 |
344262 |
�������� S.E. |
106942 |
108506 |
106966 |
114738 |
117116 |
118803 |
115158 |
128777 |
109627 |
141848 |
IRWPRICE |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
48.0 |
56.4 |
68.2 |
85.3 |
100.0 |
126.9 |
158.4 |
195.8 |
220.9 |
254.2 |
����� Baseline |
40.1 |
61.0 |
67.3 |
75.2 |
99.4 |
120.3 |
164.0 |
204.2 |
299.6 |
326.4 |
�������� S.E. |
11.9 |
18.1 |
20.1 |
24.9 |
34.1 |
45.5 |
64.3 |
82.5 |
133.1 |
173.7 |
����� Scenario 1 |
41.0 |
63.2 |
69.3 |
77.4 |
101.7 |
126.0 |
168.3 |
207.1 |
312.5 |
331.3 |
�������� S.E. |
12.0 |
17.5 |
19.8 |
24.5 |
35.0 |
44.4 |
62.2 |
80.4 |
133.9 |
175.9 |
IRYCD |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
16148761 |
16138512 |
16353946 |
17545612 |
18697203 |
19323453 |
19383195 |
21945867 |
25081725 |
26801188 |
����� Baseline |
15372011 |
16336036 |
16592102 |
17114271 |
18521717 |
19739188 |
20921209 |
21650377 |
24178838 |
26941992 |
�������� S.E. |
1063350 |
1127597 |
1118926 |
1165228 |
1255579 |
1373053 |
1460966 |
1524408 |
1787449 |
2046775 |
����� Scenario 1 |
15409091 |
16348591 |
16637895 |
17169092 |
18488699 |
19817585 |
20891687 |
21655705 |
24247013 |
26921232 |
�������� S.E. |
1092215 |
1180911 |
1124833 |
1183494 |
1282321 |
1399806 |
1495200 |
1498530 |
1703712 |
2072341 |
TBALANCE |
||||||||||
����� Actual |
64254 |
126612 |
190849 |
252671 |
233869 |
260291 |
117742 |
149182 |
186615 |
600749 |
����� Baseline |
-12064 |
96547 |
204903 |
247666 |
243306 |
256998 |
292021 |
233654 |
81778 |
557145 |
�������� S.E. |
156447 |
160653 |
183615 |
218804 |
228204 |
250681 |
267514 |
291900 |
248578 |
338083 |
����� Scenario 1 |
-213231 |
-119403 |
-72455 |
-57830 |
-56971 |
-60025 |
-41247 |
-101403 |
-160392 |
259630 |
�������� S.E. |
118499 |
123734 |
121384 |
129132 |
135799 |
137472 |
135965 |
156101 |
127913 |
179772 |
Copyrights
Copyright
for this article is retained by the author(s), with first publication rights
granted to the journal. This is an open-access article distributed under the
terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
[1] - (B.A.,
M.Sc., Ph.D., Post-Doc.) Professor Bijan Bidabad, Fars-o-Khozestan Cement Co.
economic advisor. This paper has been prepared by the order of Fars-o-Khozestan
Cement Co. and the authors acknowledge financial support of this company. The
views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of
Fars-o-Khozestan Cement Co.
presented at the 4th European Cement
Conference Barcelona, Spain 14-17 March 2004.
[2] -Dr. Nahid Kalbasi Anaraki, Fars-o-Khozestan Cement Co. economic consultant.
[3] -Dadras,
Ramin, "Measuring the technical efficiency of the cement industry in Iran,
a dissertation guided by B. H. Zonooz, Allameh University, 1999.
[4] -Sameti M., "Reducing Government Interventions", Ministry of Economic Affairs and Finance, 1995.
[5]- A committee established for confronting with shortage
of the essential goods and commodities which is under the control of the
expediency council.
[6] Bidabad B., "Designing econometric model to
measure the changes in imports and exports of the industry sector",
Chapter 5, 1996.
______ "Quantitative effects of joining WTO on Iran industrial sector", 2004.�